【紐倫港新動態•第178期】歐洲央行:歐洲急需資本市場聯盟

2021-03-01 金融讀書會

編者語:

本文是歐洲央行副主席Vítor Constâncio於2016年4月25日在歐盟委員會及歐洲中央銀行召開的主題為「歐洲金融一體化和穩定性」會議上的發言稿。文章指出,在尚未建立跨國風險分擔機制的時候,歐洲需要大幅整合和發展資本市場,以確保歐洲家庭和企業良好應對國家的經濟周期波動。歐洲要確定和追求資本市場聯盟,意味著資本市場可以在歐元區和歐盟蓬勃發展。同時,要設計一個統一的監管框架,使金融穩定性風險可控。敬請閱讀。

 

 

文/Vítor Constâncio(歐洲央行副主席)

Ladies and gentlemen,

 

An integrated and developed capital market is of key relevance to the European financial system and the economy as a whole. In my speech today, I would like to provide a foundation for this statement from two interlinked perspectives. First of all, well-functioning capital markets are particularly beneficial for an area like the euro area if they lead to what economists call 「financial risk-sharing」. At the same time, however, the process of financial integration and capital market development that can enhance such risk-sharing may be accompanied by the emergence of new financial stability risks that could undermine the envisaged benefits. Therefore, in order to reap the benefits of a true Capital Markets Union (CMU), we need to provide the conditions under which capital markets can flourish, whilst at the same time making sure that regulatory and supervisory measures keep financial stability risks in check.

 

In order to make progress on how this balance can be struck, I shall first review the case for cross-country risk-sharing via capital markets, review the evidence for the euro area and consider how it can be enhanced. Next, I shall discuss the threats to financial stability that can be associated with complementing a more bank-based financial system, like the European one, with strengthening capital markets. Third, I shall let you know my views on which macroprudential policy reforms should be considered.

 

The benefits of financial risk-sharing for the euro area

 

One of the main reasons why financial integration is beneficial is that integrated financial markets help support constant consumption growth 「in good and in bad states」 of the world.Consumption smoothing between countries, also known as risk-sharing, can increase welfare by hedging consumption against country-specific risks. In theory, in a perfectly integrated world, full risk-sharing can be achieved where consumption in regions or countries grows at a constant pace and is insensitive to local fluctuations in income and wealth.

 

Normally, high levels of risk-sharing are achieved across jurisdictions within a country, or within a federation that represents a functioning political, economic, and monetary union. For example, evidence suggests that three quarters of shocks to per capita gross product of individual states in the United States are smoothed, with about 40 percent smoothed by insurance or cross-ownership of assets, a quarter smoothed by borrowing or lending, and one-eighth smoothed by the federal transfers and grants. In other words, the contribution of markets is five times higher than the contribution of fiscal tools.Regions within federations in Europe exhibit high levels of risk-sharing, too. For example, in pre-unification Germany, virtually all shocks to per capita state gross product were smoothed. However, due to less developed capital markets than in the United States, the largest portion – 50 percent – was smoothed through the federal tax transfer and grant system, and 36 percent were smoothed through financial markets.

 

For countries in a monetary union such as the euro area, risk-sharing is particularly important because the single monetary policy is unable to address asymmetric shocks. With disjoint business cycles across countries, idiosyncratic shocks to EMU member states need to be insured through robust market or fiscal mechanisms. Reducing the volatility of aggregate consumption through various risk-sharing mechanisms can provide significant welfare gains for countries hit by specific shocks. And, by reducing internal divergences and facilitating macroeconomic adjustment, risk-sharing can be beneficial for the monetary union as a whole.

 

At this point it is quite clear that, in the foreseeable future, a number of mechanisms that have the potential to improve risk-sharing across countries will not progress quickly in Europe. For example, labour mobility will likely remain below levels achieved in common-language federations such as the United States or Germany. Similarly, building a European supra-national system of taxes and transfers to mimic the United States or the situation within some European countries is, at present, not a realistic prospect. Finally, the rules on fiscal deficits imposed by the Stability and Growth Pact will continue to set limits on national governments for smoothing large shocks.

 

For these reasons, it is more pressing than ever to boost Europe’s risk-sharing potential through financial market mechanisms. First, cross-border holdings of productive or financial assets can provide members of a currency union with insurance against idiosyncratic shocks. Second, well-functioning credit markets can contribute to smoothing consumption against relative income fluctuations, especially if most cross-border lending takes the form of direct lending to households and firms rather than of wholesale lending and borrowing in interbank markets.The conclusion is that greater progress in risk-sharing in the euro area would require significantly more developed and integrated capital markets, as well as more banks operating at a pan-European level.

 

Quantitatively, the risk-sharing benefits of integrated financial markets can be large. By far the most important source of risk sharing are cross-regional and cross-border asset holdings, that is, various forms of equity holdings and firm ownership claims. Financial integration in Europe was expected to be greatly facilitated by the introduction of the common currency. However, in the years since the introduction of the euro, progress in capital markets and credit markets integration has been uneven. At present, the cross-border ownership of assets in the EU is still limited, despite the fact that the single currency in the euro area reduced some of the information barriers and transaction costs. Corporate financing through bond and equity markets is much more limited in Europe too, with banks being the undisputed primary source of funding for firms.

 

For all these reasons, the overall contribution of markets to risk-sharing has, on average, been somewhat limited.Chart 1 demonstrates the contribution of various factors to risk-sharing over time. It shows that after the adoption of the euro, smoothing through factor income flows resulting from cross-border ownership of assets increased substantially, yet it remained on average below US levels. The notable exception is a brief period in the early-to-mid 2000s when capital markets smoothed between 30 and 40 percent of country-specific shocks to GDP. The contribution of capital markets declined substantially during the financial crisis and especially during the sovereign debt crisis. The contribution of credit markets has been lower, and it became even negative during the financial crisis when the European banking sector was particularly heavily hit. At present, almost 80 percent of the idiosyncratic shocks to a country’s economy remain unsmoothed, and changes in relative prices contribute the most to risk-sharing.

 

Contributions of various channels to risk sharing in EA, 1991 present

 

To speed up the process of capital markets and credit markets integration, two initiatives have emerged in Europe: the Banking Union and the Capital Markets Union (CMU). The Banking Union aims at a sustainable and deep integration in banking markets, through single supervision, joint resolution and common deposit insurance. Risk-sharing is particularly fostered through direct cross-border bank lending, emphasising the importance of the European Commission’s recent initiative on fostering retail financial services. The CMU, in turn, aims at mobilising capital by creating deeper and more integrated capital markets in the EU. Ideally, the CMU should achieve the completion of the single market for capital within a common-currency union. This completion is vital to reap the full benefits of risk-sharing across borders and not be limited by border effects from past institutional legacies. Overcoming these border effects is to be achieved through regulatory and non-regulatory actions, including the harmonisation of key legislation related to financial products. While the regulatory and non-regulatory actions will be instrumental in capturing market-provided risk-sharing, deeper capital markets have a particularly high potential to smooth risks across national borders.

 

Consequently, we need an ambitious CMU which requires a concrete roadmap in terms of goals and milestones. Broad objectives such as capital market development, deepening financial integration and achieving risk-sharing should be at par with specific proposals such as facilitating funding for corporates in general and for SMEs in particular. Key areas such as securitisation, insolvency regimes, securities holders』 rights and tax legislation need to be prioritised. All these are important to ensure equal treatment of users of capital markets across Member States, the very essence of a CMU.

 

Financial stability implications of enhanced risk-sharing and other aspects of capital market development

 

This brings me to the second part of my talk, where I would like to discuss the financial stability implications of enhanced risk-sharing. Indeed, financial integration and the further development of non-bank financing may also create new financial stability risks.

 

At a general level, greater integration can exacerbate the size and speed of cross-border contagion. International risk-sharing and cross-border contagion can be two sides of the same 「financial integration coin」.This explains why taking a macroprudential perspective on the financial system is extremely important for addressing potential new sources of systemic risk.

 

With respect to the banking sector, the further development of capital markets increases competition and may incentivise banks to take on more risk to maintain profitability.To ensure that there are no unintended financial stability risks, we need to strengthen the European macroprudential regulatory toolkit for banks under the Capital Requirements Directive (CRD IV)/Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR).

 

The European Commission’s review of the CRR/CRDIV will provide an opportunity to revise and complement the current macroprudential toolkit for banking at the European level. It should entail, firstly, ensuring that instruments currently available are more targeted and overlaps are eliminated; secondly, broadening the toolkit with additional instruments such as the Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR), Leverage Ratio (LR), Loan-to-Value (LTV)/Loan-to-Income (LTI) and Debt-Service-to-Income (DSTI) ratio; and thirdly, streamlining the process for notification or information procedures both in the EU and within the SSM, by revising in particular Art 458 CRR. This would simplify the co-ordination mechanism, ensuring that macroprudential authorities can decide and implement the measures in an effective, efficient and timely manner.

 

Moreover, the strong growth of non-bank financing creates new risks in a part of the financial system that is much less regulated. In particular, the investment fund sector has grown rapidly over the past few years. Between end-2009 and the first quarter of 2015, assets managed by investment funds other than money market funds almost doubled from €5.4 trillion to €10.5 trillion. Excluding valuation and reclassification effects, the sector has grown by 30 percent since 2009.

 

Importantly, this rapid growth comes together with increased risk-taking. Funds have shifted their asset allocation from higher- to lower-rated debt securities, increased the average residual maturities of debt securities』 holdings and continued to expand their exposure to emerging markets.In addition, the interconnectedness of the fund sector with the financial system, the wider use of synthetic leverage, and the increasing prevalence of demandable equity imply that the potential for a systemic impact would increase, should the investment fund industry come under stress.

 

Therefore, I want to clearly state that the financial regulatory reform has to be completed and extended through further efforts to contain risks in the shadow banking sector and to strengthen macroprudential policies.

 

Developing the macroprudential framework beyond banking

 

Please allow me to elaborate on three important aspects of this task, namely tools to address the excessive use of leverage by investment funds, tools to address liquidity risks, and a framework for macroprudential margin and haircut requirements.

 

As regards leverage in investment funds, we need to ensure that the use of leverage remains within acceptable limits. Highly leveraged funds can create and amplify systemic risk. When leverage is created through derivatives』 exposures or repo and securities lending transactions, margin calls or increasing haircuts on collateral can trigger a deleveraging by funds.Notably, such a 「margin spiral」can even occur when funds are closed and investors cannot redeem their shares at short notice. To the extent that many funds are forced to sell assets in less liquid markets and at substantial discounts, this can reinforce price falls in financial markets and become a risk of systemic nature.

 

In order to curb the use of leverage by investment funds in the EU, it is useful to distinguish between funds that are subject to the regulatory framework of the Undertakings for Collective Investments in Transferable Securities (UCITS) Directive and those subject to the Alternative Investment Fund Managers Directive (AIFMD).

 

In principle, all UCITS-funds have restrictions on the use of balance sheet and synthetic leverage. In practice, however, funds applying more complex investment strategies can calculate their use of leverage based on the Commitment Method or a Value at Risk (VaR) approach, resulting in a less stringent limit for synthetic leverage. Therefore, it is important that we examine the use of leverage by these UCITS-funds, and address any existing shortcomings in the UCITS regulations.

 

As for the alternative investment funds that operate under the AIFMD, there are no hard limits for the use of leverage. Importantly, national competent authorities do have the power to impose leverage limits under the AIFMD, but no authority has exercised this power so far. In order to put this potentially powerful macroprudential tool into practice, we need to develop an operational framework at the EU level. In this context, let me highlight three important issues.

 

First, the use of leverage within the banking system and the existing leverage ratio for banks may not always be a useful benchmark for all types of funds. Unlike bank capital, investment fund shares of open-ended funds can be an unstable source of funding when investors can withdraw their equity at short notice.

 

Second, an assessment of liquidity risk by funds should be part of the assessment of leverage. Indeed, the risk of redemptions by investors on open-ended funds can be closely related to the use of leverage.

 

Third, the framework should have a clear macroprudential perspective, providing authorities with the guidance and flexibility to set limits for groups of funds, where necessary to address a 「too many to fail」 risk.Even if investment funds are small and thus not 「too big to fail」, they may be 「systemic as a herd」, and pose a risk to financial stability due to common exposures to the same type of shock.

 

Next to tools addressing excessive leverage, we need to develop tools targeting liquidity in non-bank financial institutions. With regard to investment funds, 「liquidity spirals」 remain a risk. Such spirals could be triggered if funds were to be confronted with high redemptions or increased margin requirements, as these could result in forced selling on markets with low liquidity. To address such risks, guided stress tests could be developed jointly by ESMA, ECB and ESRB, together with national competent and macroprudential authorities, and additional intervention powers for competent authorities to deal with large scale redemptions should be discussed. As regards the latter, the UCITS directive already provides member states with the option to allow competent authorities to require the suspension of the repurchase or redemption of units in the interest of the unit-holders or of the public. We should explore whether this provision can be effectively used for macroprudential purposes.

 

Finally, the creation of leverage via derivatives and securities financing transactions (SFT) and the pro-cyclical effects of margin and haircut-setting practices in these transactions would also need to be addressed. Macroprudential authorities should be given the power to set floors on haircuts and margins on derivatives and SFT at the transaction level. Furthermore, they should be able to change these in a time-varying manner. The current margin and haircut-setting practices stimulate the build-up of leverage via these transactions in good times – when there is a tendency to under-price risk – and amplify deleveraging in bad times. While a number of policy measures aimed at limiting the pro-cyclical effects of margin and haircut-setting have already been adopted or are underway, none of these steps envisage their time-varying implementation by macroprudential authorities.

 

This new macroprudential framework could build on the current regulatory frameworks and policy recommendations as applicable to derivatives and SFTs at EU and global level. These frameworks include the FSB policy recommendations for haircuts on non-centrally cleared securities financing transactions, the BCBS-IOSCO margin requirements for non-centrally cleared derivatives and the European Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR).

 

, Standardised margin and haircut schedules exist within these frameworks, and could form the basis for setting macroprudential margins and haircuts. For example, macroprudential authorities could build on the standardised FSB/BCBS-IOSCO haircut and margin schedules, which offer a transparent means of calculating initial margins as well as explicit numerical haircut values that can be set as floors to haircut and margin calculated with internal models.(完)

 

文章來源:歐洲央行官網 2016年4月25日(本文僅代表作者觀點)

本篇編輯:姚舜達

 

【紐倫港新動態】專欄往期回顧:

第163期:香港2016年第一季度貨幣狀況、資金流動與資產市場分析

第164期:2015年香港債券市場的概況 

第165期:歐央行:歐洲貨幣政策的前景與壓力

第166期:全球金融風險加劇,發出警示信號

第167期:償付能力(Solvency)II中的監管問題

第168期:IMF:2016年《世界經濟展望》概要

第169期:國際經濟現狀與貨幣政策有效性

第170期:拉加德:果斷的行動 持久的增長

第171期:李小加:香港金融市場的新徵途

第172期:IMF:面對全球經濟挑戰,該如何出擊? 

第173期:ETF助港鞏固全球財富管理中心地位

第174期:德拉吉:利率維持不變或更低,通脹或跌至負值

第175期:英央行行長:退歐公投為英國金融穩定帶來巨大風險

第176期:港人幣中心四面受敵,港如何反敗為勝? 

第177期:厄爾尼諾現象對天然氣價格的暴漲影響

查找公眾號bashusongonfinance或掃描下方二維碼關注本平臺,查看往期文章。

關注巴曙松研究員「百度百家」專欄(網址:http://bashusong.baijia.baidu.com),請點擊底部「閱讀原文」連結。

相關焦點

  • 【紐倫港新動態•第336期】流動的歐洲:歐盟的移民經濟
    Europe’s internal borders.」in Europe, which are expected to be presented before the end of the year.雖然對難民來說,人道主義必須是最重要的考慮因素,而且基礎設施需要適應新的人口需求,一些本身也受到移民的打擊東歐國家,很可能從難民移民中受益。
  • 【紐倫港新動態·第15期】新的銀行間隔夜貸款利率即將面世
    編者語:紐約聯邦儲備銀行將在2016年的前幾個月開始發布新的銀行間隔夜貸款利率(OBFR)。新OBFR將使用聯邦基金和歐洲美元的交易數據來計算,對於美國的銀行而言,它將成為一個廣義的融資成本。文中作者回顧了隔夜聯邦基金和歐洲美元的歷史關係,並將新OBFR和聯邦基金利率做了分析和對比。作者指出,與現存利率相比,新OBFR基於更大的交易數據而產生,它將為銀行間度量隔夜貸款成本提供一種新方法。並且在正常的市場條件下,新OBFR和聯邦基金利率很可能會密切跟蹤對方。
  • 【紐倫港新動態•第96期】經濟危機後,英國銀行體系的改革——從資產負債表角度分析
    本文主要從銀行資產負債表的角度出發分析英國在經濟危機後的銀行體系改革。文章分為三個部分:第一部分從負債角度分析了銀行如何避免經濟危機悲劇的發生;第二部分從資產的角度出發分析了英國央行對貸款業務採取的措施;第三部分總結了資產負債表對銀行的重要意義。在第一部分中,Andrew Bailey首先從銀行的負債角度出發,闡述了銀行存款業務的本質,並指出銀行主要採取短期批發融資的方式規避股權槓桿帶來的風險。
  • 【第十五期】看盡世間繁華,紐倫港與世界主要城市
    2008年1月,美國《時代》周刊編輯 Micheal Elliott 的一篇長文《A Tale of Three Cities》(譯文:《三城記》)創造出了一個新的名詞: 「Ny·lon·kong」 (譯文:「紐倫港
  • 歐洲銀行業暴跌!德意志銀行股價為何達歷史最低
  • 【紐倫港新動態•第23期】薩拜因·勞滕施萊格:深化銀行監管的定性與定量化
  • 歐洲還能影響全球嗎?
    布魯塞爾效應給歐洲帶來的影響歐洲背後依靠的就是:布魯塞爾效應——布魯塞爾是歐盟總部的所在地,歐盟的很多條款與標準雖然只在歐洲 卻能影響到世界各地的制度,成為實際上的「世界大多制度」的制定者。比如說歐盟的標準會影響到東南亞印尼的木材採伐量,南美巴西蜂蜜的生產模式,中國乳製品廠家設備標準…而這背後能幫助歐盟具備這樣話語權的東西便是——市場。歐洲的市場規模之大是沒有一個公司能忽略的,而更讓許多公司無法拒絕的是歐洲的人均GDP遠高於世界上任何一個地方。其次,通常歐洲執行的各類標準都是世界上最嚴格的,而歐盟本身也具備很強大的權利。
  • 優莎娜:宣布2018年將進軍歐洲4個新市場
    點擊標題下「道道輿情」可快速關注直銷道道網訊 全球直銷行業蓬勃發展,優莎娜(USANA)也不例外,近日,優莎娜宣布將從明年起擴張歐洲4個新市場,分別為羅馬尼亞、德國、義大利和西班牙,這就意味著優莎娜全球市場從原先的20個增加到24個。
  • 【周報2016.12.05】黑天鵝投資藝術,抄底歐洲銀行業?別人恐懼時我貪婪!
    雖然在許多地方衍生品和大宗商品交易可能已經下降,但其他投行業務比如債權和貨幣交易、股票和債券資本市場以及諮詢部門的市場需求依舊高企。雖然收入增長並不如美國投行那麼好,歐洲投行的收入只有美國投行的一半多一點,但歐洲投行依舊活蹦亂跳地活著。
  • 瑞典央行宣布「升息」到0!這個正在與中國吵架的歐洲國家到底怎麼了?
    瑞典和中國的外交戰爭還在繼續,除此之外瑞典還有倆焦點比較搶眼球,一個是瑞典央行成為歐洲首個升息為零
  • 歐洲體育臺直播現五賽事
    在國際現代五項聯盟與歐洲體育臺(Eurosport)籤署了一份協議之後,今年夏天,現代五項將實現全歐洲的電視直播。
  • 歐洲明年起實行銀行業新指南,二套房政策將收緊! 反洗錢力度更大!
    點擊「西聞」微信公眾號「疫情動態」欄,獲取歐洲新冠病毒疫情實時跟蹤數據。
  • 動態快訊||2020年第33屆歐洲電影獎揭曉
    當地時間12月12日,第33屆歐洲電影獎在德國柏林揭曉了2020年最新獲獎名單,丹麥電影《酒精計劃》拔得頭籌,一舉拿下了最佳影片、最佳導演、最佳男主角
  • 2018歐洲高血壓指南發布:高血壓的定義 (1)
    2018年6月8日,第28屆歐洲高血壓與心血管保護會議在「伊比利亞半島的明珠」——西班牙巴塞隆納盛大召開;9日,本屆會議發布了由歐洲高血壓學會
  • 阿達木單抗:歐洲市場打響價格戰,國內市場幾何?
    這是山德士第五個在歐洲上市的生物仿製藥。儘管目前,HYRIMOZ僅限於在英國市場銷售,但山德士表示,HYRIMOZ很快也將在歐洲其它市場獲得上市許可。時隔一天,10月17日,三星宣布其阿達木單抗生物仿製藥「IMRALDI」在歐洲上市,由Biogen負責歐洲市場的銷售。
  • 歐洲有了新態度,這是好事
    這些歐洲官員新的表態是在歐洲從英美大醫藥公司無法按照合同及時獲供疫苗、西方內部出現齟齬紛爭的背景下發出的。俄中疫苗都因此面臨了機會。雖然歐洲有點「現用佛現燒香」,但中國人還是要看到,這是個很積極的動向。中國疫苗有了進入歐洲市場的可能性,如果成為現實,對提高中國疫苗的形象,甚至提升中國醫藥的整體形象都有好處。
  • 日本MRJ飛機意在歐洲中東市場 預計將獲新單
  • 巴西Suzano公司的Eucafluff桉木絨毛漿已被歐洲、亞洲和美國市場接受
    目前其在歐洲、亞洲和美國市場的銷售額都有所增加。Suzano公司是由SuzanoPapel e Celulose和Fibria兩家著名的巴西紙漿企業合併後成立的。Eucafluff桉木絨毛漿被認為是一種創新和可持續產品的樣板,並且已被全球主要生產商證實。
  • 美麗境界資本收購德國公司Cordenka:對價2.4億歐元 100%股權收購
    11月15日,美麗境界資本歐洲併購基金(一期)(以下簡稱「美麗境界資本」)宣布,完成首單交易,以2.4億歐元對價收購德國Cordenka公司(以下簡稱「Cordenka」)100%股權。高盛集團和霸菱銀行為此次交易牽頭提供銀團貸款,香港農銀國際參與共同投資。